1.
BAA Grouping Approach: Please provide your organization's feedback on the proposed BAA grouping methodology for market power mitigation:
a) Do you support grouping BAAs to assess competitiveness? Why or why not?
b) What changes, if any, would you recommend for the testing approach?
c) What changes, if any, would you recommend for determining the competitive LMP?
Grouping Approach
WPTF acknowledges and appreciates the effort and thought CAISO has dedicated to advancing the grouping approach for BAA-level market power mitigation. We agree that it is crucial to ensure the test accounts for all available competitive supply in order to avoid over-mitigation, which can lead to Type I errors. While we conceptually support the idea of considering all available supply when evaluating BAAs—since it represents an improvement over the current framework—we remain concerned with CAISO’s approach. It seems to combine aspects of a local market power mitigation framework with elements of a BAA-level or system-wide market power mitigation framework, creating potential inconsistencies and unintended consequences.
We believe there is likely a more suitable method for testing BAA/system-level market power that deserves further consideration. We continue to have reservations about using a constraint-based trigger for system/BAA-level market power. This trigger often activates during hours or intervals when the potential to exert market power is unlikely, as demonstrated by DMM’s analysis. This can lead to over-mitigation and Type I errors. Mitigating when market power does not exist (i.e., over mitigation) will not only suppress prices during periods of tight supply, when one would want and expect strong price signals, but also deter the entry of additional and much needed supply.
System/BAA-level market power mitigation should only be applied when the bidding behavior of a group of entities within the system or BAA intentionally manipulates prices to their advantage because they know the market will need their supply to meet load. Such conditions giving rise to the ability to exert market power needs to be predictable and persistent enough that it would be profitable for an entity to strategically bid high to artificially inflate prices; otherwise they are essentially pricing themselves out of the market and foregoing all potential revenue.
The CAISO’s approach, however, is triggered by a binding transfer constraint shadow price, which increases the MEC in a specific BAA. This does not necessarily equate to structurally uncompetitive conditions at the BAA or system level. The trigger must align with the test, and the test must address the specific issue at hand. The current approach fails to make these necessary connections, which is further discussed in response to question #5 along with potential changes to appropriately align the trigger, test, and issue.
Additionally, we seek further clarification from CAISO before providing any additional feedback on the grouping approach. Specifically, we would like to:
- Review examples of the test with actual test hours/intervals,
- Understand how, or if, virtuals are considered,
- Gain clarity on how net buyers are treated,
- See the actual formulas used to calculate the numerator and denominator in the RSI formulation, and
- Understand the type of demand used—forecasted or cleared given that the day-ahead market only clears bid-in supply against bid-in demand, which naturally serves as a market power mitigation mechanism
We would also like to better understand how the supply in an adjacent BAA is considered when testing a given BAA. For example, assume BAA 1 has a higher MEC than BAA 2 because BAA 1 has two transfer constraints that are binding between BAA 1 and other BAAs. Also assume there is a third transfer constraint with BAA 2 but it is not binding so BAA 2 has a lower MEC than BAA 1. When testing BAA 1, what amount of supply from BAA 2 is considered in the formulation? If the transfer constraint is not binding does the test include all supply up to the transfer limit or only the supply that is flowing on that transfer constraint?
Lastly, we would like to better understand how the pricing and triggering mechanism would work if you have two BAAs that have multiple transfer constraints between the two BAAs. Take for example, BAA 1 and BAA 2 and assume there are two transfer constraints (TX A and TX B) between BAA 1 and BAA 2. If both TX A and TX B are binding with $10 and $30 shadow prices respectfully, is the SMEC in BAA 1 (assume it is on the importing side) increased by $40 to create the BAA specific MEC? Also, if only TX A is binding but there is still transfer capacity on TX B, will this still result in price separation between BAA 1 and BAA 2, trigging the market power mitigation mechanism to test BAA 1 even though there is still transfer capacity between the two?
Competitive LMP
Regarding the competitive LMP, WPTF disagrees with the premise that a negative competitive LMP is appropriate. While we understand that the approach will take the higher of the competitive LMP and DEB—meaning that no resource will be mitigated to a negative value if every resource has a non-zero DEB in place. CAISO has noted previously where some resources have inappropriately low DEBs. In such cases, the more robust competitive LMP, as set today under LMPM, has helped mitigate issues arising from inaccurate DEBs. We should not design a market feature with a known flaw and assume that all resources will be protected simply because the CAISO’s DEB formulation is believed to be robust enough. Both CAISO and stakeholders recognize that there is room for improvement in the DEBs, as they do not always accurately reflect costs. Relying too heavily on the DEBs creates a significant risk.
Additionally, WPTF has concerns about using the MEC from the lowest-priced BAA added to the competitive group as the competitive LMP. The MEC is essentially the SMEC plus congestion from transfer constraints. First, we request confirmation from CAISO regarding whether a BAA can have an MEC that reflects negative transfer congestion due to a binding transfer constraint going out of the BAA. If confirmed, we do not believe it makes sense to simply use the MEC of the lowest-priced BAA. For example, if a BAA has a lower MEC, which is considered the competitive LMP, but that MEC includes negative congestion due to being upstream from a transfer constraint, it may not be appropriate to use that lower MEC value as the competitive LMP for the entire group. To illustrate, suppose the last BAA added to a group has an MEC of $10, but that MEC consists of $25 from the SMEC and -$15 from transfer constraint shadow prices. Should the competitive LMP for the larger group reflect the negative transfer constraint and use $10, or should it reflect the $25/MWh from the SMEC?
3.
Impact Test Implementation: Please comment on the proposed "impact test" in the BAA-level mitigation framework:
a) Do you support including an impact test? Why or why not?
b) What are your thoughts on impact thresholds and how they may vary based on:
• Frequently constrained areas
• System emergency conditions
• Peak versus off-peak periods
• Absolute ($/MWh) or relative (%) thresholds
WPTF generally believes that including the impact test can help reduce over-mitigation, but it is crucial that the threshold is set appropriately. Before we can opine on an appropriate threshold, it would be useful to spend more time evaluating the thresholds set by the other ISOs in context with their pricing parameters as that will obviously impact the threshold (e.g., a $300/MWh threshold with a $2,000/MWh PBC-like parameter is different than a $300/MWh threshold with a $10,000/MWh PBC-like parameter). It would also be useful to see actual sample days done with CAISO bid and pricing data to determine the distribution of impacts we may see to help inform us of an appropriate threshold.
WPTF also believes further discussion is needed to better understand how CAISO plans to use only the impact portion of a conduct and impact test. For instance, we assume that when running the impact test, CAISO will replace all bids (or possibly just the pivotal supplier bids?) with a proxy bid to determine the magnitude of impact. However, it is unclear whether the results showing a nodal LMP impact greater than the threshold would lead to mitigation of all resources or only the resource located at that LMP. Having clarity on this from CAISO would help us better assess the inclusion of an impact test.
We would also like to highlight that most other ISOs with an impact test include both the conduct and impact portions. WPTF would appreciate CAISO walking through how a conduct and impact test could work within the EDAM and then comparing it to the current approach of including only the impact portion within the existing framework as another alternative design.
5.
Other Comments: Please provide any additional feedback not addressed in the sections above.
WPTF continues to struggle with the idea of using a trigger and test that is more appropriate for local market power mitigation to be used for system/BAA-level market power mitigation. System/BAA-level market power mitigation should be applied (1) when data suggests the system/BAA is structurally uncompetitive in a persistent and predictable way and (2) when the bidding behavior of a group of entities within the system/BAA is done in such a way to artificially inflate prices to their benefit. While the current BAA-level market power mitigation may have worked well for WEIM BAAs at the onset of WEIM, it does not seem appropriate to continue down this path for a market with multiple buyers and sellers. Thus, WPTF provides below further discussion as to our concerns with the current grouping approach and highlights a potential alternative approach we believe warrants further discussion. The alternative approach also leverages the existing LMPM framework but more appropriately tests the counterflow on the binding constraints that are causing the price separation for competitive conditions.
The grouping approach proposed by the CAISO continues to lean on the existing framework which hinges on price separation occurring between two BAAs and then testing the BAA that has the “higher” price for market power. First, the BAA with a higher price may be price separated from the other BAA not because of the way the entities within its BAA are bidding. As suggested by the DMMs analysis, this can be due to the fact that another BAA has surplus renewable generation and is wanting to export as much as possible to other BAAs and/or is curtailing generation. This does not seem to be a situation where the entities within the receiving BAA are bidding in a way to exert market power within its own BAA. Rather this is a situation where due to the resource mix in another BAA, the receiving BAA now is subject to market power mitigation.
Furthermore, the price separation occurs due to binding transfer constraints. Thus, if another MW of transfer capacity was made available, there would not be price separation. This is akin to an internal transmission constraint binding and causing price separation within the system. Under this situation though, with the LMPM, the CAISO tests for uncompetitive conditions based on the supply and demand for counterflow on that constraint because it’s the shadow price of the binding constraint causing prices to separate. Similarly here, the BAA prices separate due to the shadow price on a transfer constraint that is added to the SMEC to create BAA specific MECs. The difference in pricing is solely due to the transfer constraint. Thus, we believe its worth discussing if its more appropriate to evaluate the competitiveness of counterflow on the binding transfer constraint since that is what is driving the price separation rather than using the price impact from the binding transfer constraint as a trigger to then turn around and test the supply and demand for the entire BAA (or group of BAAs). Specifically, the transfer constraints would be treated and tested in the same manner as binding internal transmission constraints. We recognize there are some details that would need to be discussed, such as what supply to be considered counterflow supply, but believe it warrants exploration as an alternative solution to the grouping approach.
Lastly, WPTF would like to understand how other ISOs test for BAA/System level market power alongside local market power. WPTF continues to be concerned that due to the interaction of the two different mitigation tests and methodologies, there will be unintended consequences. For example, two different competitive LMPs does not make sense. Lowering one just because of the math of the other does not make sense either. It is our understanding that no other ISO has two different approaches for BAA/system level market power and local market power.